Snapshot of - POLES

From IAMC-Documentation
Revision as of 17:45, 7 August 2020 by Rineke Oostenrijk (talk | contribs) (Edited automatically from page POLES setup.)
(diff) ← Older revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)
Jump to navigation Jump to search

Archive of POLES, version: ENGAGE (other versions are in use in other applications)

Reference card - POLES

The reference card is a clearly defined description of model features. The numerous options have been organized into a limited amount of default and model specific (non default) options. In addition some features are described by a short clarifying text.

Legend:

  • not implemented
  • implemented
  • implemented (not default option)

About

Name and version

POLES ENGAGE (other versions are in use in other applications)

Institution

JRC - Joint Research Centre - European Commission (EC-JRC), Belgium, http://ec.europa.eu/jrc/en/.

Documentation

POLES documentation consists of a referencecard and detailed model documentation

Process state

published

Model scope and methods

Model documentation: Model scope and methods - POLES

Model type

  • Integrated assessment model
  • Energy system model
  • CGE
  • CBA-integrated assessment model

Geographical scope

  • Global
  • Regional

Objective

POLES was originally developed to assess energy markets, combining a detailed description of energy demand, transformation and primary supply for all energy vectors. It provides full energy balances on a yearly basis using frequent data updates to as to deliver robust forecasts for both short and long-term horizons. It has quickly been used, in the late 90s, to assess energy-related CO2 mitigation policies. Over time other GHG emissions have been included (energy and industry non-CO2 from the early 2000s), and linkages with agricultural and land use models have been progressively implemented.

Solution concept

  • Partial equilibrium (price elastic demand)
  • Partial equilibrium (fixed demand)
  • General equilibrium (closed economy)

Solution horizon

  • Recursive dynamic (myopic)
  • Intertemporal optimization (foresight)

Solution method

  • Simulation
  • Optimization
  • Recursive simulation

Anticipation

Myopic

Temporal dimension

Base year:2015, time steps:Yearly, horizon: 2015-2100

Note: Energy markets: yearly step Power generation: 2-hour time steps in representative days

Spatial dimension

Number of regions:66

Note: Complete energy balances: 57 countries / regions covering the World, including detailed EU28, all OECD countries and main non-OECD countries Fossil fuel supply: 80 countries / regions

Time discounting type

  • Discount rate exogenous
  • Discount rate endogenous

Policies

  • Emission tax
  • Emission pricing
  • Cap and trade
  • Fuel taxes
  • Fuel subsidies
  • Feed-in-tariff
  • Portfolio standard
  • Capacity targets
  • Emission standards
  • Energy efficiency standards
  • Agricultural producer subsidies
  • Agricultural consumer subsidies
  • Land protection
  • Pricing carbon stocks

Socio-economic drivers

Model documentation: Socio-economic drivers - POLES

Population

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Population age structure

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Education level

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Urbanization rate

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

GDP

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Income distribution

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Employment rate

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Labor productivity

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Total factor productivity

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)

Autonomous energy efficiency improvements

  • Yes (exogenous)
  • Yes (endogenous)


Macro-economy

Model documentation: Macro-economy - POLES

Economic sector

Industry

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Energy

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Transportation

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Residential and commercial

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Agriculture

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Forestry

  • Yes (physical)
  • Yes (economic)
  • Yes (physical & economic)

Other economic sector

  • Services (economic)

Macro-economy

Trade

  • Coal
  • Oil
  • Gas
  • Uranium
  • Electricity
  • Bioenergy crops
  • Food crops
  • Capital
  • Emissions permits
  • Non-energy goods

Cost measures

  • GDP loss
  • Welfare loss
  • Consumption loss
  • Area under MAC
  • Energy system cost mark-up

Note: Investments: supply-side only

Categorization by group

  • Income
  • Urban - rural
  • Technology adoption
  • Age
  • Gender
  • Education level
  • Household size

Institutional and political factors

  • Early retirement of capital allowed
  • Interest rates differentiated by country/region
  • Regional risk factors included
  • Technology costs differentiated by country/region
  • Technological change differentiated by country/region
  • Behavioural change differentiated by country/region
  • Constraints on cross country financial transfers

Resource use

Coal

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Conventional Oil

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Unconventional Oil

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Conventional Gas

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Unconventional Gas

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Uranium

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Bioenergy

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Water

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Raw Materials

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)

Land

  • Yes (fixed)
  • Yes (supply curve)
  • Yes (process model)


Technological change

Energy conversion technologies

  • No technological change
  • Exogenous technological change
  • Endogenous technological change

Energy End-use

  • No technological change
  • Exogenous technological change
  • Endogenous technological change

Material Use

  • No technological change
  • Exogenous technological change
  • Endogenous technological change

Agriculture (tc)

  • No technological change
  • Exogenous technological change
  • Endogenous technological change

Other technological change

  • Energy Conversion - Exogenous Technological Change

Energy

Model documentation: Energy - POLES

Behaviour

Activity drivers depend on income per capita and energy prices via elasticities. Energy demand depends on activity drivers, energy prices and technology costs. Primary energy supply depends on remaining resources, production cost and price effects.

Energy technology substitution

Energy technology choice

  • No discrete technology choices
  • Logit choice model
  • Production function
  • Linear choice (lowest cost)
  • Lowest cost with adjustment penalties

Energy technology substitutability

  • Mostly high substitutability
  • Mostly low substitutability
  • Mixed high and low substitutability

Energy technology deployment

  • Expansion and decline constraints
  • System integration constraints

Energy

Electricity technologies

  • Coal w/o CCS
  • Coal w/ CCS
  • Gas w/o CCS
  • Gas w/ CCS
  • Oil w/o CCS
  • Oil w/ CCS
  • Bioenergy w/o CCS
  • Bioenergy w/ CCS
  • Geothermal power
  • Nuclear power
  • Solar power
  • Solar power-central PV
  • Solar power-distributed PV
  • Solar power-CSP
  • Wind power
  • Wind power-onshore
  • Wind power-offshore
  • Hydroelectric power
  • Ocean power

Hydrogen production

  • Coal to hydrogen w/o CCS
  • Coal to hydrogen w/ CCS
  • Natural gas to hydrogen w/o CCS
  • Natural gas to hydrogen w/ CCS
  • Oil to hydrogen w/o CCS
  • Oil to hydrogen w/ CCS
  • Biomass to hydrogen w/o CCS
  • Biomass to hydrogen w/ CCS
  • Nuclear thermochemical hydrogen
  • Solar thermochemical hydrogen
  • Electrolysis

Refined liquids

  • Coal to liquids w/o CCS
  • Coal to liquids w/ CCS
  • Gas to liquids w/o CCS
  • Gas to liquids w/ CCS
  • Bioliquids w/o CCS
  • Bioliquids w/ CCS
  • Oil refining

Refined gases

  • Coal to gas w/o CCS
  • Coal to gas w/ CCS
  • Oil to gas w/o CCS
  • Oil to gas w/ CCS
  • Biomass to gas w/o CCS
  • Biomass to gas w/ CCS

Heat generation

  • Coal heat
  • Natural gas heat
  • Oil heat
  • Biomass heat
  • Geothermal heat
  • Solarthermal heat
  • CHP (coupled heat and power)

Grid Infra Structure

Electricity

  • Yes (aggregate)
  • Yes (spatially explicit)

Gas

  • Yes (aggregate)
  • Yes (spatially explicit)

Heat

  • Yes (aggregate)
  • Yes (spatially explicit)

CO2

  • Yes (aggregate)
  • Yes (spatially explicit)

Hydrogen

  • Yes (aggregate)
  • Yes (spatially explicit)


Energy end-use technologies

Passenger transportation

  • Passenger trains
  • Buses
  • Light Duty Vehicles (LDVs)
  • Electric LDVs
  • Hydrogen LDVs
  • Hybrid LDVs
  • Gasoline LDVs
  • Diesel LDVs
  • Passenger aircrafts

Freight transportation

  • Freight trains
  • Heavy duty vehicles
  • Freight aircrafts
  • Freight ships

Industry

  • Steel production
  • Aluminium production
  • Cement production
  • Petrochemical production
  • Paper production
  • Plastics production
  • Pulp production

Residential and commercial

  • Space heating
  • Space cooling
  • Cooking
  • Refrigeration
  • Washing
  • Lighting

Land-use

Model documentation: Land-use - POLES

Land cover

  • Cropland
  • Cropland irrigated
  • Cropland food crops
  • Cropland feed crops
  • Cropland energy crops
  • Forest
  • Managed forest
  • Natural forest
  • Pasture
  • Shrubland
  • Built-up area

Agriculture and forestry demands

  • Agriculture food
  • Agriculture food crops
  • Agriculture food livestock
  • Agriculture feed
  • Agriculture feed crops
  • Agriculture feed livestock
  • Agriculture non-food
  • Agriculture non-food crops
  • Agriculture non-food livestock
  • Agriculture bioenergy
  • Agriculture residues
  • Forest industrial roundwood
  • Forest fuelwood
  • Forest residues

Agricultural commodities

  • Wheat
  • Rice
  • Other coarse grains
  • Oilseeds
  • Sugar crops
  • Ruminant meat
  • Non-ruminant meat and eggs
  • Dairy products

Emission, climate and impacts

Model documentation: Emissions - POLESClimate - POLESNon-climate sustainability dimension - POLES

Greenhouse gases

  • CO2 fossil fuels
  • CO2 cement
  • CO2 land use
  • CH4 energy
  • CH4 land use
  • CH4 other
  • N2O energy
  • N2O land use
  • N2O other
  • CFCs
  • HFCs
  • SF6
  • PFCs

Pollutants

  • CO energy
  • CO land use
  • CO other
  • NOx energy
  • NOx land use
  • NOx other
  • VOC energy
  • VOC land use
  • VOC other
  • SO2 energy
  • SO2 land use
  • SO2 other
  • BC energy
  • BC land use
  • BC other
  • OC energy
  • OC land use
  • OC other
  • NH3 energy
  • NH3 land use
  • NH3 other

Climate indicators

  • Concentration: CO2
  • Concentration: CH4
  • Concentration: N2O
  • Concentration: Kyoto gases
  • Radiative forcing: CO2
  • Radiative forcing: CH4
  • Radiative forcing: N2O
  • Radiative forcing: F-gases
  • Radiative forcing: Kyoto gases
  • Radiative forcing: aerosols
  • Radiative forcing: land albedo
  • Radiative forcing: AN3A
  • Radiative forcing: total
  • Temperature change
  • Sea level rise
  • Ocean acidification

Carbon dioxide removal

  • Bioenergy with CCS
  • Reforestation
  • Afforestation
  • Soil carbon enhancement
  • Direct air capture
  • Enhanced weathering

Climate change impacts

  • Agriculture
  • Energy supply
  • Energy demand
  • Economic output
  • Built capital
  • Inequality

Co-Linkages

  • Energy security: Fossil fuel imports & exports (region)
  • Energy access: Household energy consumption
  • Air pollution & health: Source-based aerosol emissions
  • Air pollution & health: Health impacts of air Pollution
  • Food access
  • Water availability
  • Biodiversity



Model Documentation - POLES

This documentation describes the POLES-ADVANCE version of the model, developed for the purposes of this project.

For the version of the model used in other JRC publications, see POLES in the JRC website.

1) Model scope and methods - POLES

POLES (Prospective Outlook on Long-term Energy Systems) is a global recursive dynamic simulation model of the energy system and covers all anthropogenic greenhouse gases emissions.

It allows to simulate a wide range of energy policies, be they on the demand side or on the supply sector. It displays a high regional resolution and sectoral representation, and provide endogenous simulation of all steps of the energy system by vector and sector: final energy demand, transformation (including power generation), trade, primary supply, international and final user prices.

  • The model describes full energy balances for multiple countries and regions covering the whole world, and primary supply for a different geographical disaggregation, as well as energy commodities trade and trade routes.
  • It operates on a yearly time step and benefits from frequently updated databases, allowing it to capture the most recent developments of energy markets in various countries / regions.
  • Additional modules allow covering GHG emissions from industrial sources; agriculture and land-use emissions are derived from linkages with specialized models.

<xr id="fig:POLES_1"/> below gives a schematic view of the POLES model. The red boxes are the main assumptions, calibration and scenario settings; the green box represents the energy balance resolution by country / region and the blue boxes represent the trade and key outputs (demand, supply, emissions).

<figure id="fig:POLES_1">

General scheme of POLES

</figure>

Key input assumptions are population and growth of GDP per capita. The economic activity is then derived by the model at sectoral level, depending on economic growth and energy prices: economic sector value added, passengers and goods mobility, building stocks, etc..

Other critical assumptions are energy resources by type and localization.

The model has been used in cross-model comparison exercises and it has been tested in the framework of establishing diagnostic indicators to characterize model responses kriegler2015di. It has been used in several studies looking at transformation pathways of the energy system for the 21st century and the consequences in terms of emissions mitigation policies and technologies mix EC 2003EC 2006kitous2010tr. More recently, it has been used by the European Commission in its Global Energy and Climate Outlook.

1.1) Model concept, solver and details - POLES

POLES is a recursive dynamic simulation model. Variables are either calculated directly or are calculated based on the previous years' values, to which are applied the evolution of explanatory variables.

The economic decisions (investment and utilisation rate) are based on the current state of knowledge of parameters (costs of technologies, prices, ...) or with a myopic anticipation of future costs and constraints for the agent, also considering vintage, resource potentials and other inertia.

The model does not use foresight but rather myopic anticipation. Some foresight can be forced by using alternative runs as input files.

The model is developed on the Vensim software.

1.3) Temporal dimension - POLES

The model runs with a 1 year time step, usually from 1990 to 2050, the 1990-2015 period being almost entirely set by data and used for calibration. In the context of the ADVANCE project it has been run up to 2100.

1.4) Spatial dimension - POLES

Energy and emissions balances

The geographical representation is based on the importance of countries in energy consumption and GHG emissions. POLES describes full energy and emissions balances for 57 geographical units: 45 individual countries and 12 residual regions covering the World. Countries include all OECD (1990) countries and large non-OECD countries. All EU28 Member States and nearly all G20 countries are thus explicitly represented. The 45 individual countries are the following:

  • EU28 Member States
  • Norway
  • Switzerland
  • Iceland
  • Turkey
  • Russia
  • Ukraine
  • Canada
  • USA
  • Mexico
  • Brazil
  • Japan
  • South Korea
  • China
  • India
  • Indonesia
  • Egypt
  • South Africa

Additional individual countries are present in more recent versions of the model (Australia, New Zealand, Argentina, Chile, Iran, Saudi Arabia, Thailand, Malaysia, Vietnam).

<figure id="fig:POLES_2">

POLES - the World in 57 energy balances

</figure>

Land use and renewable energies potentials (wind, solar, biomass) follow the geographical representation of the energy balances.

The international air and maritime bunkers are represented separately.

Energy demand at World level, and related emissions, is then the sum of all regions and bunkers.

Fossil fuels supply

The fossil fuels supply side is more detailed, with all important producing countries being represented allowing a very precise description of the supply side and a good understanding of the related issues at stake.

Oil and gas productions are described for 80 producers.

<figure id="fig:POLES_3">

POLES - 80 oil and gas producers

</figure>

Coal production distinguishes 74 producers, including an infra-national disaggregation for large producers (USA, China, Australia, India).


Trade

Producing regions and consuming regions are linked through energy markets.

  • Oil producers supply a single world "pool" market
  • Large gas producers export towards 14 regional consuming markets; small gas producers only supply domestic consumption
  • Large coal producers export towards 15 regional consuming markets; small coal producers only supply domestic consumption
  • Solid or liquid biofuels producers export towards a single world "pool" market
  • A single world production of uranium is modelled

    1.5) Policy - POLES

The POLES model is used to simulate:

  • GHG policies
    • Country/region objective: Implementation of carbon (or CO2eq) pricing (iterative calibration)
    • Cumulated GHG/CO2 buget: Regional differentiation of constraint and carbon pricing permitting to reduce emissions within budget (iterative calibration)
    • Carbon leakage (limited)
  • Energy taxation policies
    • GHG-related pricing policies (carbon pricing)
    • other environmental taxes (e.g. introduction of environmental damage tax on non-conventional fuels production)
    • fossil fuel subsidies (possibility to phase out)
    • introduction of renewable fuels subsidy
  • Support policies for specific technologies
    • Electricity generation feed-in tariffs
    • Low interest loans or subsidies to capital cost in purchase of energy consuming equipment
    • Acceleration of the penetration emerging vehicle technologies
    • Modal shifts in passenger transport
  • Efficiency standards
    • fuel efficiency standards in vehicles
    • penetration of low-energy consuming buildings
  • Openness to investment
    • Reactivity to prices on exploration and production in oil and gas producing regions
    • Discount rates in investment
    • National preference in the sourcing of fossil fuels or national resource management in domestic fossil fuels production

Policies included are updated regularly to reflect the current state of affairs at country and sector level. See for example the list of policies in the GECO 2016 scenarios.

The model has been used extensively to study climate mitigation scenarios:

  • It has specifically been used to inform UNFCCC international negotiations, looking at global and regional climate mitigation scenarios and assessing the economic costs (and, in tandem with other models, the economic impacts) of the transition to a low-carbon economy: with relation to the Kyoto Protocol and beyondEC-JRC 2007russ2007po, in the negotiations around the COPs in Copenhagen and DohaEC-JRC 2005EC-JRC 2009riahi2015lo and more recently on the Paris AgreementEC-JRC 2015vandyck2016a.

The two main drivers, population and GDP, are exogenous.

2.1) Population - POLES

Population is an exogenous driver in POLES. The standard source used is the UN World Population ProspectsUN 2015 (latest), medium fertility scenario.

The model distinguishes only one population group.

2.2) Economic activity - POLES

GDP

GDP is exogenous and is derived from various international sourcesWB 2015. Latest work used GDP assumptions from:

Consistency with population is checked.

An on-going work will allow to connect POLES to the macro-econometric model MAGE (CEPII institute / JRC) through an energy factor in the production function that will link dynamically GDP, energy intensity and energy prices.

All other economic activities variables (value added, mobility, surfaces, ...) are endogenously calculated in POLES.

3) Macro-economy - POLES

The key marco-economic assumptions are derived from population and GDP.

Starting from historical data, which capture local specificities, sectoral economic activity variables are calculated:

  • sectoral value added: depend on the level of development of the country/region, given by GDP per capita (industrialization phase followed by service-based economy);
  • industrial physical production: depend on demand, which itself depends on the level of development;
  • mobility (for passengers and for goods): depend on the cost of transport compared to income, and is declined in equipment rates and degree of utilisation of this equipment;
  • buildings surfaces: depend on households size (occupancy per dwelling) and surface per dwelling, both depending on personal income.

<figure id="fig:POLES_4">

Share of value-added as a function of GDP per capita

</figure>

3.1) Production system and representation of economic sectors - POLES


Sectoral disaggregation

All economic activity variables are endogenously derived from GDP per capita and energy prices. The energy demand in POLES is endogenously derived from sector-specific drivers: economic activity, end-user energy prices and policies, including time lagged effects. The modeling also considers vintage and fuel / technology substitution constraints.

The model differentiates the following sectors:

  • Agriculture (economic activity: value added)
  • Industry (value added and physical production), with 4 sub-sectors:
    • Steel, Chemistry, Non-metallic minerals and Other industry; energy uses and non-energy uses of fuels are differentiated.
  • Services (value added): substitutable energy and captive electricity needs are differentiated
  • Residential (surface, occupation rate): needs for space heating, water heating, space cooling, cooking, appliances and lighting are differentiated
  • Transport (mobility), with 4 sub-sectors:
    • Road, Rail, Water, Air; additionally, international maritime bunkers and international air bunkers are differentiated.
    • The model differentiates passengers and goods transport, and various transport types: car, motorbikes, light duty vehicle, heavy duty vehicles.
    • Road vehicles are differentiated by engine (ICE, electric, hybrids, fuel cell) and fuel (oil products, biofuels, electricity, hydrogen, gas).
  • In addition, own-energy uses and losses in transformation (power, synthetic fuels, ..) are explicitly considered.

Historical data on energy demand, activity variables and fuel prices are updated at least once a year from various sources. Energy demand and prices come mostly from: Eurostat, IEA, Enerdata. Energy demand data can be available up to year-1.


Behavioural change

Behavioral changes is captured in 2 ways in POLES:

  • a change of the economic activity (applies to Residential and Transport): this change depends on income and energy prices through appropriate elasiticies;
  • a change in the rate of use of energy consuming equipment: this change depend on energy prices through short-term elasticities.

    4) Energy - POLES

POLES describes the world energy system, covering all energy carriers.

The model includes the following modules:

  • Energy supply: production of fossil fuels and biomass and international trade
  • Energy transformation: refining of fuels, production of synthetic fuels (e.g. liquid biofuels, hydrogen), power generation
  • Final energy demand: industry, buildings, transport, agriculture

The technological description of the model varies according to the detail of the representation of each sector.

4.1) Energy resource endowments - POLES

The model distinguishes different geographical representations according to the resource considered.

Supply is linked to demand regions via trade:

  • Oil: producers all export to single global market "pool"
  • Gas: large producers export towards 14 importing regions; small producers only supply domestic demand
  • Coal: large producers export towards 14 importing regions; small producers only supply domestic demand
  • Solid biomass: producers supply domestic demand or export towards a global market depending on the relative cost of production
  • Liquid biofuels: similar to solid biomass
  • Uranium: single global supply cost curve
  • Primary electricity (hydro, solar, wind): country-specific renewables potentials for power generation for domestic electricity demand

4.1.1) Fossil energy resources - POLES

The POLES model differentiates various types of fossil fuels:

  • oil: conventional, tar, heavy and oil shale / onland & shallow, deepwater, artic;
  • gas: conventional, shale gas / onland & shallow, deepwater and artic;
  • coal: steam and coke.

The description below gives elements for oil, but they can be extended to gas and coal.

<figure id="fig:POLES_5">

Static aggregated oil production cost curve

</figure>

While this figure gives an aggregated static cost curve, the model actually uses dynamic cost curve per resource type integrating the cost of energy needs for production for each production country/ region. Consequently POLES fossil fuel cost curves thus evolve over time, by region and with the scenario settings (for instance: a CO2 pricing will affect the production cost of tar sands).

The supply module transforms resources into reserves through discovery effort (exploration and drilling) that depends on remaining resources, the (dynamic) production cost curve and international fuel prices, through elasticities that capture openness to investment and resource management strategies.

Reserves are then turn into production depending on remaining reserves, the (dynamic) production cost curve and international fuels prices.

<figure id="fig:POLES_6">

Reserves discovery process in POLES (URR: ultimate Recoverable Resources, DISOIL: Discovery of oil)

</figure>

The model has been used in several studies of the role of fossil fuel resources and in low-carbon transition pathwaysbauer2015codowling2012th, particularly in the aspects of energy securityandrews-speed2014comccollum2013foEC-JRC 2013.

Sources of information include: BGRBGR 2015, USGSUSGS 2013, IEAIEA 2015, EnerdataEnerdata 2015, WECWEC 2013a, MIT, industry estimates

4.1.2) Uranium and other fissile resources - POLES

Uranium resources used in LWRs are represented at World level only (sources: IAEA / NEA Red Book, CEA estimates, ..). An Uranium price is derived from a global supply cost curve. LWR capacity development is also constrained by the amount of remaining resources. Fast breeders development is contrained by the production of waste from LWR.

Sources of information include: IAEA/NEA Red BookOECD 2014, estimates from CNRS/CEA/LPSC, ..

4.1.3) Bioenergy - POLES

Primary biomass resources for energy uses are classified in 3 categories for all countries/regions:

  • energy crops (in agricultural area, grassland)
  • short rotation crops (cellulosic)
  • forest residues (cellulosic)

Energy crops are dedicated to 1st generation biofuels, the 2 other categories are used in all other energy uses (a further split of biomass feedstocks has been implemented for Europe using information from the model GREEN-X). POLES uses by default a simplified modeling of land use to estimate the potential of these resources: land available, yields (evolve over time, based on historical evolution), share of harvest/land that can be allocated to energy uses.

<figure id="fig:POLES_7">

Biomass resource use in POLES

</figure>

POLES also uses in a standard way exogenous estimates of potentials: for instance a soft linkage with the model GLOBIOM/G4M has been implemented that goves potential estimates and cost curves for all World regions (with the model GREEN-X at EU level). Biomass supply cost curves are attached to the various biomass types and come from GREEN-X, GLOBIOM and other sources.

The conversion into liquid biofuels distinguishes first generation (agricultural energy crops) and second generation (cellulosic).

The model has been used in several studies to examine the future use of biomass as an energy sourcemubareka2014an, bio-energy tradematzenberger2015fukranzl2013me and the role of biomass in emissions mitigationluderer2013thvuuren2010bi.

Information sources include: FAOFAO 2015.

4.1.4) Non-biomass renewables - POLES

Hydro resources

Hydro resources are defined for all countries / regions. They constraint the development of hydro power (which depends on identified projects and average power production costs).

Sources of information include: WECWEC 2013a, IEAIEA 2015.


Solar resources

Solar resources are defined as the maximum amount of solar energy that can harvested for the energy system. Solar energy in urban areas depends on the rooftop surface, solar energy in non-urban areas depends on land-use and distance to consuming centres. The resource is then used in the energy system depending on the economic conditions, considering network constraints. The model uses mostly inside calculation considering solar irradiation, land use, population density and urban areas.

Source: Pietzcker et alpietzcker2014us


Wind resources

The model distinguishes between total resource and technical potential that is considered as harvestable, depending on distance to consuming centres and depths (for offshore resource). Total resources come from NREL estimates, technical potential can be internally calculated or also derived from NREL estimates. This potential is then used in the energy system depending on the economic conditions, considering network constraints.

Source: NRELNREL 2013


The system integration of renewables in the model has been tested in several studiespietzcker2016sydesprés2016st.

4.2) Energy conversion - POLES

The model distinguishes the following energy conversion processes:

  • Electricity production: detailed representation of power generation capacities and production
  • Heat production: coverage of distributed means (cogeneration, solar), no coverage of centralized means
  • Gaseous fuels: gas (natural gas and methane recovery), hydrogen
  • Liquid fuels: crude oil refineries; liquid fuels production from coal, gas and solid biomass
  • Solid fuels: coal (and coke), biomass

4.2.1) Electricity - POLES

The electricity system consists of 3 main parts:


Demand load curve

The model considers 2 typical days (winter and summer), each split into 12 time arrays of 2 hours each. The demand load curve is derived from the sum of sectoral electricity demand load curves (end uses), net trade and losses.

In the POLES-ADVANCE version these two days are the base of 27 days each, which are the combinations of low, medium and high situations for demand, wind production and solar production. This way, extreme situations are taken into account in the operation and planning of the power system.


Operation (production and storage)

The model considers first the non-dispatchable energy sources (hydro, wind, solar). The residual load is met by dispatchable generators based on their variable costs (efficiency and fuel cost, including additional taxes or financial support schemes). A proxy for the power price is computed based on the marginal producer's cost. Storage technologies and demand response (which shift a part of the load to another time slice of a given day) are used if the within-day spread of two-hourly prices compensates their efficiency losses. The number of full load hours of each production and storage technology is the weighted aggregation of these 54 days. Some over production can appear when the non-dispatchable productions (also taking into account a minimum power output for must-run technologies) exceed demand. When possible it is stored; otherwise it is curtailed and the load factors of wind and solar are decreased accordingly.


Capacity planning

The planning of new capacities needs to address expected future electricity needs (based on a rolling ten-year extrapolation) while considering the upcoming decommissioning of existing plants (with vintage) and the special contribution of wind and solar (non-dispatchable).

The 648 time-slices per year (54*12) are organised in seven blocks with expected capacity factors of 8760 hours, 8030 hours, 6570 hours, 5110 hours, 3650 hours, 2190 hours and 730 hours. The associated number of full load hours define different total production costs for each of these blocks. This defines the theoretical technology market shares together with coefficients that are calibrated to replicate historical technology mix. Non-dispatchable wind and solare are first determined, in competition with all technologies. However, they don't produce constantly on all seven blocks. Once their capacity is decided (limited by a maximum potential), the remaining need per investment block is updated with the actual production of wind and solar (which is deduced from the current participation of wind of solar in each block).

The dispatchable technologies are then planned based on the remaining capacity needs for each investment block, the theoretical market shares and the resource constraints for some technologies.

<figtable id="POLES_tab_1">

Electricity production technologies in POLES
Fuel Technologies
Nuclear Conventional nuclear design
New nuclear design ("Generation IV")
Coal Pulverized fluidized coal
Pulverized fluidized coal with CCS
Integrated coal gasification with combined cycles
Integrated coal gasification with combined cycles with CCS
Conventional coal thermal turbine
Conventional lignite thermal turbine
Gas Conventional gas thermal turbine
Gas turbine
Gas combined cycles
Gas combined cycles with CCS
CHP (decentralized)
Gas fuel cell (decentralized)
Oil Conventional oil thermal turbine
Oil combined cycles
Biomass Conventional biomass thermal turbine
Biomass gasification
Biomass gasification with CCS
Hydro Run-of-river
Reservoir (lake)
Small hydro (<10 MW)
Wind Onshore
Offshore
Solar Utility PV
Distributed PV (decentralized)
Solar thermal power
Solar thermal power with storage
Ocean Tidal & wave ocean
Geothermal Geothermal power
Other Hydrogen fuel cell (decentralized)
Storage Pumped hydro
Compressed air
Batteries (lithium ion)
Demand-side solutions Vehicle-to-grid
Load shifting

</figtable>

In addition to the technologies mentioned in the figure above, one POLES version includes further detail of biomass technologies in the EU, based on work with the GREEN-X model.


Electricity prices

Total production cost is the sum of fixed cost (investment, discount rate, fixed O&M) and variable cost (fuel cost, efficiency, variable O&M), including further taxes or financial support schemes. Investment costs evolve with learning functions (exogenous, endogenous 1 factor, endogenous 2 factors). Efficiency is exogenous. Fuel costs are derived from endogenous fuel prices and assumptions on taxation policies.

Finally the POLES model calculates electricity prices from system production cost for base load (used to set the price for industry) and peak load (used to set the price for residential-services-transport).

Information sources include: Enerdata, Eurostat, IEAWEO 2015, ENTSO-E, ETDB, WECWEC 2013a, EC-JRCEC-JRC 2014.


The model has been used to study the power system costs of mitigation policies under various configurationsduscha2013cogriffin2013wh. The sysytem integration of variable renewables in the model has been tested in several studiesdesprés2016stpietzcker2016sy.

4.2.2) Heat - POLES

Steam can be produced by heat and power cogeneration (CHP) plants and steam-only plants, the inputs of which are accounted for within the "own use" of the energy sector. The production of steam is not simulated explicitly. The model checks that the evolution of steam demand is consistent with the evolution of the "own use" of the energy sector and with the availability of CHP compatible power plants.

Other heat-related demand is satisfied by boilers and heaters using other energy vectors (oil, gas, coal, biomass, electricity, solar heat).

4.2.3) Gaseous fuels - POLES


Gas

Natural gas domestic production and imports directly supply gas for consumption. Additional gas production can come from:

  • Urban waste methane recovery:
  • Underground coal methane recovery
  • Gas production fugitive emissions recovery
  • Coke oven gas is captured in the final energy demand of the iron and steel sector

All three are determined by the effect of carbon pricing on the relevant emissions source.


Hydrogen

The model uses a complete module to represent hydrogen production (14), transport and use in various sectors: transport (fuel cells or thermal use), but also in stationary uses in industry and buildings (fuel cells or blending with natural gas). Water electrolysis from grid is coupled with the electricity load curve (hydrogen is produced preferentially during base load).

<figure id="fig:POLES_8">

The hydrogen module in POLES

</figure>


Hydrogen in the energy system in particular has been the subject of studies with the modelEC 2006.

4.2.4) Liquid fuels - POLES


Oil products

Crude oil production is transformed into oil products (one energy carrier represented in the model) with a refineries efficiency.


Biomass to Liquids

The POLES model differentiates 4 biomass-to-liquids production technologies, each described by cost, efficiency estimates and use of feedstock type:

  • 1st generation bioethanol and biodiesel;
  • 2nd generation bioethanol and biodiesel.

The use of the different liquid biofuels is restricted by blending constraints (with oil products) in the various sectors.

Information sources include: IEA, OECD, DEFRA, DFT, JEC


Coal to Liquids

The Coal-to-liquid production (Fischer Tropsch) is described by one generic technology (cost and efficiency) to which a CCS module can be added.

The development of CTL depends on the distance between production cost and the oil price.

Information sources include IEA, EIA.


Gas to Liquids

Similarly to CTL production, the gas-to-liquids production is described by one generic technology (cost and efficiency) to which a CCS module can be added.

The development of GTL depends on the distance between production cost and the oil price.

Information sources include IEA, EIA.

4.2.5) Solid fuels - POLES


Coal

Coal primary supply (imported or domestically produced) is directly fed to consumption.

Sectors consume steam/thermal coal or coking coal (iron and steel sector). The coking coal transformation is captured in final energy demand.


Biomass

Biomass primary supply (imported or domestically produced; in energy units) is directly fed to consumption.

Solid biomass can be used to produce liquid biofuels or electricity in energy transformation; or in direct combustion in final demand.

4.2.6) Grid, pipelines and other infrastructure - POLES

Own use of the energy sector

Fossil fuel extraction

POLES describes explicitely the direct energy use, and the corresponding emissions, of the following fuels: - tar sands - extra heavy oil - oil shale

All other energy use related to fossil fuel extraction is captured in one single factor, expressed by fuel as a % of the energy production and kepy constant over time at the last historical value.

Refineries

The energy use in the refining sector is captured through a coefficient, expressed as a % of the demand for oil product, kept constant over time at the last historical vakue

Others

Other own-energy uses are captured through a coefficient, expressed by fuel as a % of primary energy demand, kept constant over time at the last historical value.


Losses in Transport & Distribution

Grids and pipelines are not modelled explicitly. Pipelines are captured through transport costs as compared to other trade routes.

Losses in T&D are expressed by fuel as a % of final energy use, and by default kept constant at the last historical value.

They can be adjusted depending on the scenario (for instance to capture a decrease in electricity losses, ..).

4.3) Energy end-use - POLES

Energy end-use is distinguished in demand for:

  • industrial sectors;
  • buildings (residential and services);
  • transport (road, rail, water, air);
  • agriculture.

Information sources include: Enerdata, Eurostat, IEA, IISI, World Bank. Sector-specific information is frawn from: IISI, EIA, Odyssee, IRF, UIC, UNCTAD.

4.3.1) Transport - POLES

Several modes are distinguished in the model (road, rail, water, air), for both passenger and goods transport.

Mobility depends on income and prices, with all steps (activity variables and unit consumptions) using specific equations and parameters. In particular, in the case of cars, the model uses the notion of "budgetary coefficient" that constraints the mobility (dynamic elasticities) through a maximum share of yearly income that can be dedicated to energy purchases.

Passenger mobility is the sum of individual modes, which are indirectly interdependant (though opposite behaviors to prices) and capped by saturation effects (max number of vehicles per capita, ..). Goods mobility is calculated at national level and then split across modes, apart from Maritime bunkers which is calculated only at Global level.

The competition across vehicle types (6 types of vehicles in cars and trucks: conventional ICE, electric, plugin hybrid, H2 fuel cell, H2 thermal, gas) uses a multinominal logit function that depends on the total cost for the user, considering fixed cost (investment, life-time, user discount rate) and variable cost (consumption per km, fuel price), and is constrained by infrastructure developments for refueling stations.

Fuel price (that affects mobility, consumption per unit and competition across technologies) includes end-user energy taxation policies, which include carbon prices.

Finally, biodiesel and bioethanol are differentiated, both capped by blending constraints depending on the oil products (gasoline, diesel, kerosene, heavy fuel).

The table below gives a general overview of the transport module in POLES.

<figtable id="POLES_tab_3">

The transport module in POLES
Mobility Mode Vehicles/scope Fuel used Engines Activity Link to income Link to fuel prices
Passengers Road Cars Liquids (oil products, biofuels), electricity, gas, hydrogen ICE, hybrid, electric, CNG, hydrogen fuel cell, hydrogen thermal vehicles; mileage; occupation "+" "-"
Motorbikes Liquids ICE vehicles; mileage "+" "-"
Buses Liquids, electricity, gas, hydrogen ICE, hybrid, electric, CNG, hydrogen fuel cell, hydrogen thermal passenger-kilometers "+" "+"
Rail Oil products, electricity, coal passenger-kilometers "+"
Air National Liquids passenger-kilometers "+" "-"
International Liquids passenger-kilometers "+" "-"
Goods Road Heavy trucks Liquids, electricity, gas, hydrogen ICE, hybrid, electric, CNG, hydrogen fuel cell, hydrogen thermal ton-kilometres; mileage; load "+" "-"
Light trucks Liquids, electricity, gas, hydrogen ICE, hybrid, electric, CNG, hydrogen fuel cell, hydrogen thermal vehicles; mileage; load "+" "-"
Rail Liquids, electricity, coal ton-kilometres "+"
Waterways Oil products "+"
Maritime International Liquids ton-kilometres "+" "-"

</figtable>


Transport energy use and associated emissions in the context of climate mitigation strategies have been studied in the model in several publicationsflachsland2011clgirod2013cl.

4.3.2) Residential and commercial sectors - POLES


Residential

In POLES the energy demand in the residential building sector depends on the building stock and the fuel prices. The building stock is based on the evolution of surface needs, which depend on number of persons per household and on the surface per dwelling, both dependent on income per capita. The module simulates the need for new surface, considering lifetime of existing buildings. In addition it calculates an amount of renovated buildings in the existing stock.

Energy demand is grouped into several energy services. For each service, a useful energy need is calculated; it is then converted into final energy demand with competition between fuels. The competition across fuels (logit) is based on total cost for the user (fixed cost, fuel utilization efficiency), it is constrained by the lifetime of the existing equipment, and is calibrated on historical data of energy demand and prices. The following services are modelled:

  • Space heating: depend on surfaces, energy prices and HDD (heating degree-days). Final energy demand is split into three sub-categories representing the diffusion of 3 building types of different levels of insulation (applying to new and renovated surfaces).
  • Water heating: depend on surfaces, energy prices and HDD.
  • Cooking: depend on surfaces and energy prices.
  • Space cooling: final demand of electricity directly calculated, based on diffusion of air conditioning equipment (depends on income, CDD) and efficiency of use (depends on income, CDD (cooling degree-days), electricity prices and insulation).
  • Appliances: final demand of electricity directly calculated, depends on income and electricity prices.
  • Lighting: depend on surfaces, electricity prices.

Additionally, the contribution of solar heating (in space and water heating) and of decentralized means of electricity production (heat and power cogeneration, decentralized PV or fuel cells) are taken into account: competition with other energy fuels or with grid electricity (based on relative cost for the consumer, including possible support schemes for some technologies). Coal and traditional biomass are phased out based on their low efficiency.

Fuels considered are: electricity, oil, gas, coal, modern biomass, traditional biomass, hydrogen, steam.

Electricity can be produced locally (with cogeneration, decentralized PV or fuel cells) and then competes with network electricity.


Services

For the Services sector, the building stock is represented by sectoral value added. Similar to surfaces in the Residential sector, new surfaces and renovation of the existing stock is represented by shares of value added.

Energy demand is grouped into:

  • Substitutable energy demand (heating, cooking, hot water): total theoretical energy demand depends on sectoral value added and average energy prices. The sectoral value added is split into 3 levels of energy efficiency to capture the diffusion of insulation technology that substitutes for final energy consumption (applying to new and renovated surfaces). Diffusion drivers are GDP per capita, energy cost for the user (investment, fuel price, subsidies) and investment in insulation. The competition across fuels (logit) is based on total cost for the user, and is constrained by the lifetime of the existing equipment; it is calibrated on historical data of energy demand and prices.
  • Captive electricity: depends on total sectoral value added and electricity prices.

Solar heat, decentralized electricity production, coal and traditional biomass are represented in a similar way to Residential.


The impacts of climate change on energy use and comfort in the residential sector have been studied with the model in several publicationsdowling2013thEC-JRC 2014.

4.3.3) Industrial sector - POLES

The industry is represented in POLES through different sectors and processes.

The general modeling describes energy needs per sector / process dependent on an activity variable and energy prices. Total demand of energy depends on the activity variable and energy prices.

The activity variable is sectoral value added, or for the steel industry physical production of tons of steel. The latter depend on national demand and a global market, on which countries compete based on existing production capacities, the dynamics of the local market and the energy cost. The role of electrical steel increases with the amount of steel being recycled, blast furnace being the difference between total production needs and the contribution of electrical arc furnaces.

Competition across fuels / boilers (multinomial logit) takes place between oil, gas, coal, biomass and purchased steam based on costs for the user, considering the lifetime of existing equipment. The competition calibrated on historical data on prices and market shares.

Electricity needs, that also depend on the activity variable and electricity prices, can affect the need for other fuels through increased efficiency of the industrial processes.

The different industral sectors and processes are shown in the figure below.

<figtable id="POLES_tab_2">

The industrial sectors in POLES
Sector Process Activity variable Fuel, energy use Fuel, non-energy use
Steel Blast furnace tons Electricity, oil, gas, coal, biomass coke
Electrical tons Electricity
Non-metallic minerals value added Electricity, oil, gas, coal, biomass, hydrogen, steam
Chemistry value added Electricity, oil, gas, coal, biomass, hydrogen, steam oil, gas, coal, biomass
Other industry value added Electricity, oil, gas, coal, biomass, hydrogen, steam

</figtable>

Note that the steel industry equations describe physical production, which depends on national demand and a global market, on which countries compete based on existing production capacities, the dynamics of the local market and the energy cost. The role of electrical steel increases with the amount of steel being recycled, blast furnace being the difference between total production needs and the contribution of electrical arc furnaces.

4.3.4) Other end-use - POLES


Agriculture

Energy use of the agriculture, fisheries and forestry sector is captured with the value added of agriculture and income per capita.

4.4) Energy demand - POLES

Energy demand from the various end-uses (industry, buildings, transport, agriculture) is aggregated into totals that have to be supplied by the energy transformation module.

The following energy vectors are modelled:

  • oil
  • gas
  • coal
  • biofuels (solid: traditional, modern; transport: liquid biofuels: transport)
  • electricity
  • marketed heat
  • hydrogen

Total demand of energy depends on the relevant activity variable (surfaces, mobility needs, value added) and sectoral energy prices. Competition across fuels takes place based on costs for the user (also considering the lifetime of existing equipment); it is calibrated on historical data on prices and market shares. Additional trends are used to model non-cost drivers (autonomous technological trends or non-price policies such as efficiency standards).

4.5) Technological change in energy - POLES

Technological change in the various sectors takes place through competition in the new capacity planning ("gap", multinominal logit), which depends on expected utilisation costs of the competing technologies (myopic anticipation, no perfect foresights). Technological change is constrained by the vintage of existing capital stock ("unscrapped consumption") and resource availability. In addition to upgrading possibility, accelerated retirement can be considered in some specific cases (e.g. some coal plants in the power generation sector).

<figure id="fig:POLES_8">

Schematic of the energy needs and depreciation procedure in POLES

</figure>

Costs usually consider fixed costs (investment, lifetime, O&M, discount rate) and variable costs (fuel price, efficiency, O&M).

Investment costs can be exogenously set or endogenously simulated through learning curves (1 or 2-factors learning curves) depending on the sector.

It must be noted that the competition also considers, in addition to the cost component, a "reality parameter" that is calibrated (directly in the model or with external procedures) to replicate the historical situation given used cost estimates. This parameter is essential to compensate for imperfect cost estimates or to capture drivers of economic decisions that are poorly or not at all represented in the model (national industrial policy choices, etc..). The model also includes the possibility to test "network effect" for new technologies (accelerated adoption beyond some market share threshold).

Future scenarios with technological change have been studied with the model in several reportsEC 2003EC 2006wiesenthal2012acriqui2015mi.

5) Land-use - POLES

Land surfaces are disaggregated in the following categories:

  • The surfaces dedicated to Agricultural activities (crops, meadows, pastures). They evolve with an annual trend using population and agricultural productivity (exogenous); the growth decreases when land use is close to saturation).
  • The surface of forests evolves to account for the expansion of the agriculture surface.
  • Urban areas evolve with an annual trend using urban population and GDP growth.
  • Inland water and desert areas evolve with exogenous trends.
  • Finally grassland surface (grasslands, shrublands, savannas, natural vegetation mosaic) is the difference between the total country / region area and all other surfaces.


Energy biomass is produced from the following surfaces:

  • 1st generation biofuels: agricultural area, grassland
  • other uses: forest area (for forest residues), grassland (for short rotation crops)

Yields evolve over time, based on historical evolution.

GHG emissions from agriculture and land-use are derived from a soft linkage with the GLOBIOM model.

See Bioenergy - POLES

Information sources include: FAO.

6) Emissions - POLES

All Kyoto defined greenhouse gases are included POLES: CO2, CH4, N2O, SF6, HFCs, PFCs. Note that HFCs and PFCs are respectively gathered into one category, the corresponding global warming potentials (GWP) being the average ratio between historical inventories expressed in CO2e and in grams, the ratio are then kept constant.

The model directly covers all emissions from the energy sector and the industry sector. Other emissions (agriculture, land use) come from a soft linkage with the GLOBIOM/G4M model.

GHG policies affect these emissions: energy CO2 is derived from the changes in the energy sector induced by the policy, other emissions are affected by specific marginal abatement cost curves (MACCs).

Information sources include: UNFCCC GHG inventoriesUNFCCC 2015, IPCC Assessment Reports, EDGAR databaseEC-JRC 2015, IEAIEA 2015, EIA, FAOFAO 2015.


The model has been used extensively to study climate mitigation scenariosEC-JRC 2007EC-JRC 2009vandyck2016akriegler2015ma. See the Policy page for more examples.

6.3) Carbon dioxide removal (CDR) options - POLES

The following carbon dioxide removal options are modelled:

  • CCS in power generation: with coal, gas, biomass
  • CCS in synthetic liquid fuels production: from coal, gas, solid biomass
  • CCS in hydrogen production: with coal, gas, biomass
  • CCS in industry: with combustion of coal, biomass
  • Net sinks in LULUCF: from lookup curves linking carbon price, biomass production cost and biomass demand (share of biomass potential used)

    7) Climate - POLES

The model produces annual greenhouse gases emissions (and, in certain model versions, air pollutants and short-lived climate species).

The climate effects are calculated thanks to the MAGICC diagnostics toolbox using model outputs.


Most studies with the model are on climate mitigation. However, the impacts of climate change on energy use and comfort in the residential sector have also been studied with the modeldowling2013thEC-JRC 2014.

8) Non-climate sustainability dimension - POLES

Metals

Demand for tons of steel is represented in order to inform the iron and steel industry sector. This provides a better activity indicator instead of value added and allows for the study of changes in the geographical allocation of steel-making due to energy price changes and carbon leakage. See Industrial sector - POLES.


Water

In certain versions of the POLES model, water use associated to the production of electricity is modelled. A water use is associated per technology and provides projections of water needs based on installed capacities per technology.


Additionally, the model has been used for studying the side-effects of the energy system and associated emissions in terms of air pollutionrafaj2012co and healthmarkandya2009pu.

9) Appendices - POLES

9.2) Data - POLES

Synthetic view of POLES data sources:

Macro-economic drivers

Population

  • UN (2015, medium fertility)

GDP

  • World Bank (2015), EC (2015), IMF (2016), OECD (2013, see also Dellink et al. 2014)

Value added

  • World Bank (2015); projection endogenous

Mobility, vehicles, households, tons of steel

  • Sectoral databases; projections endogenous


Energy resources

Oil, gas, coal

  • BGR (2014), USGS (2013), WEC (2013), sectoral databases

Uranium

  • OECD (2014)

Biomass

  • EU: Green-X model1
  • Non-EU: GLOBIOM model

Hydro

  • Enerdata (2015)

Wind, solar

  • NREL (2013), Pietzcker (2014)


Energy balances

Reserves, production

  • BP (2015), Enerdata (2015), IEA (2015); projections endogenous

Demand by sector and fuel, transformation (including. power), losses

  • Enerdata (2015), IEA (2015); projections endogenous


Energy prices

International energy prices, prices to consumer

  • EIA (2016), Enerdata (2015), IEA (2015); projections endogenous


GHG emissions

Energy CO2

  • Derived from energy balances; endogenous

Other GHG Annex 1

  • UNFCCC (2015); projections endogenous, and derived from data from GLOBIOM

Other GHG Non-Annex 1 (excl. LULUCF)

  • EDGAREC-JRC 2015; projections endogenous, and derived from data from GLOBIOM

LULUCF Non-Annex 1

  • FAO (2015); projections endogenous, and derived from data from GLOBIOM


Technology costs

The model's learning curves based on literature, including but not only: EC JRC (2014), IEA Technology Roadmaps, WEC (2013), TECHPOL database (developed in several European research projects: SAPIENT, SAPIENTIA, CASCADE MINTS - see for instance: [1])

10) References - POLES

EDGAR EC-JRC 2015 testing OECD/NEA 2014 OECD 2014 testing

{{#scite:

|reference=EC-JRC 2015 
|type=database
|citation text=Emissions Database for Global Atmospheric Research (EDGAR), v4.2 and v4.2 FT2010. European Commission - Joint Research Centre. 2015. [2]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=FAO 2015
|type=database
|citation text=Emissions Land Use database FAOSTAT. Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations. 2015. [3]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=IMF 2016
|type=database
|citation text=World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund. 2016. [4]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=OECD 2013
|type=database
|citation text=Economic Outlook No 93, Long term Baseline Projections. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. June 2013. [5]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=OECD 2014 
|type=report
|title=Uranium 2014: Resources, Production and Demand. A Joint Report by the OECD Nuclear Energy Agency and the International Atomic Energy Agency. NEA No. 7209. [6]
|author=Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; Nuclear Energy Agency|+sep=;
|publisher=OECD
|year=2014
|institution=OECD/NEA
|address=Paris, France

}} {{#scite:

|reference=NREL 2013
|type=database
|citation text=Global CFDDA-based Onshore and Offshore Wind Potential Supply Curves by Country, Class, and Depth (quantities in GW and PWh). National Renewable Energy Laboratory. 2013. [7]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=UN 2015
|type=database
|citation text=Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. World Population Prospects, the 2015 Revision. United Nations. 2015. [8]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=UNFCCC 2015
|type=database
|citation text=Greenhouse Gas Inventory Data, Flexible Queries. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. 2015. [9]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=USGS 2013
|type=database
|citation text=World Petroleum Assessment. US Geological Survey. 2013. [10], [11]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=WB 2015
|type=database
|citation text=World data bank, World development indicators. World Bank. 2015. [12]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=WEC 2013a
|type=database
|citation text=World Energy Resources, 2013 Survey. World Energy Council. 2013. [13]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=Enerdata 2015
|type=database
|citation text=Global Energy & CO2 Data. Enerdata. 2015. [14]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=IEA 2015
|type=database
|citation text=IEA online energy statistics. International Energy Agency. 2015. [15]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=BGR 2015
|type=database
|citation text=Energy Study 2015. Reserves, Resources and Availability of Energy Resources. 2015. [16]

}} {{#scite:

|reference=WEO 2015
|type=database
|citation text=‌WEO-2015 Power Generation Assumptions. International Energy Agency. 2015. [17]

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=després2016st
|type=journal-article
|title=Storage as a flexibility option in power systems with high shares of variable renewable energy sources: a POLES-based analysis
|author=Jacques Després;Silvana Mima;Alban Kitous;Patrick Criqui;Nouredine Hadjsaid;Isabelle Noirot|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Economics
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2016
|doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2016.03.006
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0140-9883

}} {{#scite:

|reference=pietzcker2016sy
|type=journal-article
|title=System integration of wind and solar power in integrated assessment models: A cross-model evaluation of new approaches
|author=Robert C. Pietzcker;Falko Ueckerdt;Samuel Carrara;Harmen Sytze de Boer;Jacques Després;Shinichiro Fujimori;Nils Johnson;Alban Kitous;Yvonne Scholz;Patrick Sullivan;Gunnar Luderer|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Economics
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2016
|doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2016.11.018
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0140-9883

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2014

|type=report
|author=EC-JRC
|year=2014
|title=ETRI 2014 - Energy Technology Reference Indicator projections for 2010-2050. [18]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Petten, The Netherlands

}} {{#scite:

|reference=pietzcker2014us
|type=journal-article
|title=Using the sun to decarbonize the power sector: The economic potential of photovoltaics and concentrating solar power
|author=Robert Carl Pietzcker;Daniel Stetter;Susanne Manger;Gunnar Luderer|+sep=;
|journal=Applied Energy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2014
|volume=135
|pages=704-720
|doi=10.1016/j.apenergy.2014.08.011
|subject=Energy(all);Civil and Structural Engineering|+sep=;
|issn=0306-2619

}} {{#scite:WEC 2013b

|type=report
|author=WEC
|year=2014
|title=World Energy Perspective, Cost of Energy Technologies: 2013 Survey. [19]
|institution=World Energy Council
|address=London, United Kingdom

}} {{#scite:

|reference=duscha2013co
|type=journal-article
|title=Costs of meeting international climate targets without nuclear power
|author=Vicki Duscha;Katja Schumacher;Joachim Schleich;Pierre Buisson|+sep=;
|journal=Climate Policy
|publisher=Informa UK Limited
|year=2013
|volume=14
|issue=3
|pages=327-352
|doi=10.1080/14693062.2014.852018
|subject=Atmospheric Science;Environmental Science(all)|+sep=;
|issn=1469-3062;1752-7457|+sep=;

}} {{#scite:

|reference=griffin2013wh
|type=journal-article
|title=White Knights: will wind and solar come to the rescue of a looming capacity gap from nuclear phase-out or slow CCS start-up?
|author=Bradford Griffin;Pierre Buisson;Patrick Criqui;Silvana Mima|+sep=;
|journal=Climatic Change
|publisher=Springer Nature
|year=2013
|volume=123
|issue=3-4
|pages=623-635
|doi=10.1007/s10584-013-0963-5
|subject=Atmospheric Science;Global and Planetary Change|+sep=;
|issn=0165-0009;1573-1480|+sep=;

}}

{{#scite:EC 2015

|type=report
|author=DG ECFIN
|year=2015
|title=The 2015 Ageing Report: Economic and budgetary projections for the 28 EU Member States (2013-2060). [20]
|institution=European Commission
|address=Brussels, Belgium

}} {{#scite:

|reference=dellink2014co
|type=journal-article
|title=Consequences of Climate Change Damages for Economic Growth
|author=Rob Dellink;Ramiro Parrado;Kelly de Bruin;Elisa Lanzi;Jean Château;Francesco Bosello|+sep=;
|journal=OECD Economics Department Working Papers
|publisher=Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development  (OECD)
|year=2014
|doi=10.1787/5jz2bxb8kmf3-en
|issn=1815-1973

}} {{#scite:

|reference=markandya2014lo
|type=journal-article
|title=Low climate stabilisation under diverse growth and convergence scenarios
|author=A. Markandya;M. González-Eguino;P. Criqui;S. Mima|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2014
|volume=64
|pages=288-301
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.046
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=vandyck2016a 
|type=journal-article
|title=A global stocktake of the Paris pledges: Implications for energy systems and economy
|author=Toon Vandyck;Kimon Keramidas;Bert Saveyn;Alban Kitous;Zoi Vrontisi|+sep=;
|journal=Global Environmental Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2016
|volume=41
|pages=46-63
|doi=10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2016.08.006
|subject=Ecology;Geography, Planning and Development;Global and Planetary Change;Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0959-3780

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2015

|type=report
|author=Kitous A.; Keramidas K.|+sep=;
|year=2014
|title=Analysis of scenarios integrating the INDCs. [21]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Seville, Spain

}} {{#scite:

|reference=riahi2015lo
|type=journal-article
|title=Locked into Copenhagen pledges — Implications of short-term emission targets for the cost and feasibility of long-term climate goals
|author=Keywan Riahi;Elmar Kriegler;Nils Johnson;Christoph Bertram;Michel den Elzen;Jiyong Eom;Michiel Schaeffer;Jae Edmonds;Morna Isaac;Volker Krey;Thomas Longden;Gunnar Luderer;Aurélie Méjean;David L. McCollum;Silvana Mima;Hal Turton;Detlef P. van Vuuren;Kenichi Wada;Valentina Bosetti;Pantelis Capros;Patrick Criqui;Meriem Hamdi-Cherif;Mikiko Kainuma;Ottmar Edenhofer|+sep=;
|journal=Technological Forecasting and Social Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=90
|pages=8-23
|doi=10.1016/j.techfore.2013.09.016
|subject=Management of Technology and Innovation;Applied Psychology;Business and International Management|+sep=;
|issn=0040-1625

}} {{#scite:

|reference=veysey2016pa
|type=journal-article
|title=Pathways to Mexico’s climate change mitigation targets: A multi-model analysis
|author=Jason Veysey;Claudia Octaviano;Katherine Calvin;Sara Herreras Martinez;Alban Kitous;James McFarland;Bob van der Zwaan|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Economics
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2016
|volume=56
|pages=587-599
|doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2015.04.011
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0140-9883

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2005

|type=report
|author=Russ H; Ciscar Martinez J; Szabo L|+sep=;
|year=2005
|title=Analysis of Post-2012 Climate Policy Scenarios with Limited Participation. [22]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Seville, Spain

}} {{#scite:

|reference=criqui2012eu
|type=journal-article
|title=European climate—energy security nexus: A model based scenario analysis
|author=Patrick Criqui;Silvana Mima|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2012
|volume=41
|pages=827-842
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2011.11.061
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}} {{#scite:

|reference=edenhofer 2010th
|type=journal-article
|title=The Economics of Low Stabilization: Model Comparison of Mitigation Strategies and Costs
|author=Ottmar Edenhofer ;Brigitte Knopf;Terry Barker;Lavinia Baumstark;Elie Bellevrat;Bertrand Chateau;Patrick Criqui;Morna Isaac;Alban Kitous;Socrates Kypreos;Marian Leimbach;Kai Lessmann;Bertrand Magne;Serban Scrieciu;Hal Turton;Detlef P. van Vuuren|+sep=;
|journal=The Energy Journal
|publisher=International Association for Energy Economics (IAEE)
|year=2010
|volume=31
|issue=01
|doi=10.5547/issn0195-6574-ej-vol31-nosi-2
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0195-6574

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2009

|type=report
|author=Russ H; Ciscar Martinez J; Saveyn B; Soria Ramirez A; Szabo L; Van Regemorter D|+sep=;
|year=2005
|title=Economic Assessment of Post-2012 Global Climate Policies - Analysis of Gas Greenhouse Gas Emission Reduction Scenarios with the POLES and GEM-E3 models. [23]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Seville, Spain

}} {{#scite:

|reference=russ2009in
|type=journal-article
|title=Insights on different participation schemes to meet climate goals
|author=Peter Russ;Tom van Ierland|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Economics
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2009
|volume=31
|pages=S163-S173
|doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2009.07.009
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0140-9883

}} {{#scite:

|reference=stankeviciute2008en
|type=journal-article
|title=Energy and climate policies to 2020: the impacts of the European “20/20/20” approach
|author=Loreta Stankeviciute;Patrick Criqui|+sep=;
|journal=International Journal of Energy Sector Management
|publisher=Emerald
|year=2008
|volume=2
|issue=2
|pages=252-273
|doi=10.1108/17506220810883243
|subject=Energy(all);Strategy and Management|+sep=;
|issn=1750-6220

}} {{#scite:

|reference=stankeviciute2008th
|type=journal-article
|title=The fundamentals of the future international emissions trading system
|author=Loreta Stankeviciute;Alban Kitous;Patrick Criqui|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2008
|volume=36
|issue=11
|pages=4272-4286
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2008.07.035
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2007

|type=report
|author=Russ H; Wiesenthal T; Van Regemorter D; Ciscar Martinez J|+sep=;
|year=2005
|title=Global Climate Policy Scenarios for 2030 and beyond - Analysis of Greenhouse Gas Emission Reduction Pathway Scenarios with the POLES and GEM-E3 Models. [24]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Seville, Spain

}} {{#scite:

|reference=russ2007po
|type=journal-article
|title=Post-Kyoto CO2 emission reduction: The soft landing scenario analysed with POLES and other world models
|author=Peter Russ;Patrick Criqui|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2007
|volume=35
|issue=2
|pages=786-796
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2006.03.010
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}} {{#scite:

|reference=criqui2006im
|type=journal-article
|title=Impacts of Multi-gas Strategies for Greenhouse Gas Emission Abatement: Insights from a Partial Equilibrium Model
|author=Patrick Criqui;Peter Russ;Daniel Deybe|+sep=;
|journal=The Energy Journal
|publisher=International Association for Energy Economics (IAEE)
|year=2006
|volume=SI2006
|issue=01
|doi=10.5547/issn0195-6574-ej-volsi2006-nosi3-12
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0195-6574

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=criqui2015mi
|type=journal-article
|title=Mitigation strategies and energy technology learning: An assessment with the POLES model
|author=P. Criqui;S. Mima;P. Menanteau;A. Kitous|+sep=;
|journal=Technological Forecasting and Social Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=90
|pages=119-136
|doi=10.1016/j.techfore.2014.05.005
|subject=Management of Technology and Innovation;Applied Psychology;Business and International Management|+sep=;
|issn=0040-1625

}} {{#scite:

|reference=wiesenthal2012a 
|type=journal-article
|title=A model-based assessment of the impact of revitalised R&D investments on the European power sector
|author=Tobias Wiesenthal;Arnaud Mercier;Burkhard Schade;Hrvoje Petric;Paul Dowling|+sep=;
|journal=Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2012
|volume=16
|issue=1
|pages=105-112
|doi=10.1016/j.rser.2011.07.139
|subject=Renewable Energy, Sustainability and the Environment
|issn=1364-0321

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=matzenberger2015fu
|type=journal-article
|title=Future perspectives of international bioenergy trade
|author=Julian Matzenberger;Lukas Kranzl;Eric Tromborg;Martin Junginger;Vassilis Daioglou;Chun Sheng Goh;Kimon Keramidas|+sep=;
|journal=Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=43
|pages=926-941
|doi=10.1016/j.rser.2014.10.106
|subject=Renewable Energy, Sustainability and the Environment
|issn=1364-0321

}} {{#scite:

|reference=mubareka2014an
|type=report
|title=An Integrated Modelling Framework for the Forest-based Bioeconomy
|author=Sarah Mubareka;Ragnar Jonsson;Francesca Rinaldi;Giulia Fiorese;Jesús San-Miguel-Ayanz;Ola Sallnäs;Claudia Baranzelli;Roberto Pilli;Carlo Lavalle;Alban Kitous|+sep=;
|institution=Cold Spring Harbor Laboratory Press
|year=2014
|doi=10.1101/011932

}} {{#scite:

|reference=kranzl2013me
|type=incollection
|title=Medium and Long-Term Perspectives of International Bioenergy Trade
|author=Lukas Kranzl;Vassilis Daioglou;Andre Faaij;Martin Junginger;Kimon Keramidas;Julian Matzenberger;Erik Tromborg|+sep=;
|year=2013
|pages=173-189
|booktitle=Lecture Notes in Energy Vol.17: International Bioenergy Trade
|publisher=Springer Nature
|doi=10.1007/978-94-007-6982-3_8

}} {{#scite:

|reference=luderer2013th
|type=journal-article
|title=The role of renewable energy in climate stabilization: results from the EMF27 scenarios
|author=Gunnar Luderer;Volker Krey;Katherine Calvin;James Merrick;Silvana Mima;Robert Pietzcker;Jasper Van Vliet;Kenichi Wada|+sep=;
|journal=Climatic Change
|publisher=Springer Nature
|year=2013
|volume=123
|issue=3-4
|pages=427-441
|doi=10.1007/s10584-013-0924-z
|subject=Atmospheric Science;Global and Planetary Change|+sep=;
|issn=0165-0009;1573-1480|+sep=;

}} {{#scite:

|reference=vuuren2010bi
|type=journal-article
|title=Bio-Energy Use and Low Stabilization Scenarios
|author=Detlef P. van Vuuren;Elie Bellevrat;Alban Kitous;Morna Isaac|+sep=;
|journal=The Energy Journal
|publisher=International Association for Energy Economics (IAEE)
|year=2010
|volume=31
|issue=01
|doi=10.5547/issn0195-6574-ej-vol31-nosi-8
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0195-6574

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=bauer2015co
|type=journal-article
|title=CO2 emission mitigation and fossil fuel markets: Dynamic and international aspects of climate policies
|author=Nico Bauer;Valentina Bosetti;Meriem Hamdi-Cherif;Alban Kitous;David McCollum;Aurélie Méjean;Shilpa Rao;Hal Turton;Leonidas Paroussos;Shuichi Ashina;Katherine Calvin;Kenichi Wada;Detlef van Vuuren|+sep=;
|journal=Technological Forecasting and Social Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=90
|pages=243-256
|doi=10.1016/j.techfore.2013.09.009
|subject=Management of Technology and Innovation;Applied Psychology;Business and International Management|+sep=;
|issn=0040-1625

}} {{#scite:

|reference=andrews-speed2014co
|type=journal-article
|title=Conflict and cooperation over access to energy: Implications for a low-carbon future
|author=Philip Andrews-Speed;Coby van der Linde;Kimon Keramidas|+sep=;
|journal=Futures
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2014
|volume=58
|pages=103-114
|doi=10.1016/j.futures.2013.12.007
|subject=Development;Business and International Management;Sociology and Political Science|+sep=;
|issn=0016-3287

}} {{#scite:

|reference=mccollum2013fo
|type=journal-article
|title=Fossil resource and energy security dynamics in conventional and carbon-constrained worlds
|author=David McCollum;Nico Bauer;Katherine Calvin;Alban Kitous;Keywan Riahi|+sep=;
|journal=Climatic Change
|publisher=Springer Nature
|year=2013
|volume=123
|issue=3-4
|pages=413-426
|doi=10.1007/s10584-013-0939-5
|subject=Atmospheric Science;Global and Planetary Change|+sep=;
|issn=0165-0009;1573-1480|+sep=;

}} {{#scite:EC-JRC 2013

|type=report
|author=Kitous A; Saveyn B; Gervais S; Wiesenthal T; Soria Ramirez A|+sep=;
|year=2013
|title=Analysis of Iran Oil Embargo. [25]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Seville, Spain

}} {{#scite:

|reference=dowling2012th
|type=journal-article
|title=The benefit from reduced energy import bills and the importance of energy prices in GHG reduction scenarios
|author=Paul Dowling;Peter Russ|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Economics
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2012
|volume=34
|pages=S429-S435
|doi=10.1016/j.eneco.2011.12.010
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0140-9883

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=girod2013cl
|type=journal-article
|title=Climate impact of transportation A model comparison
|author=Bastien Girod;Detlef P. van Vuuren;Maria Grahn;Alban Kitous;Son H Kim;Page Kyle|+sep=;
|journal=Climatic Change
|publisher=Springer Nature
|year=2013
|volume=118
|issue=3-4
|pages=595-608
|doi=10.1007/s10584-012-0663-6
|subject=Atmospheric Science;Global and Planetary Change|+sep=;
|issn=0165-0009;1573-1480|+sep=;

}} {{#scite:

|reference=flachsland2011cl
|type=journal-article
|title=Climate policies for road transport revisited (II): Closing the policy gap with cap-and-trade
|author=Christian Flachsland;Steffen Brunner;Ottmar Edenhofer;Felix Creutzig|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2011
|volume=39
|issue=4
|pages=2100-2110
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.053
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}}

{{#scite:EC-JRC 2014

|type=report
|author=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|year=2014
|title=Climate Impacts in Europe. The JRC PESETA II Project. [26]
|institution=European Commission - Joint Research Centre
|address=Brussels, Belgium

}} {{#scite:

|reference=dowling2013th
|type=journal-article
|title=The impact of climate change on the European energy system
|author=Paul Dowling
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2013
|volume=60
|pages=406-417
|doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2013.05.093
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=kriegler2015di
|type=journal-article
|title=Diagnostic indicators for integrated assessment models of climate policy
|author=Elmar Kriegler;Nils Petermann;Volker Krey;Valeria Jana Schwanitz;Gunnar Luderer;Shuichi Ashina;Valentina Bosetti;Jiyong Eom;Alban Kitous;Aurélie Méjean;Leonidas Paroussos;Fuminori Sano;Hal Turton;Charlie Wilson;Detlef P. Van Vuuren|+sep=;
|journal=Technological Forecasting and Social Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=90
|pages=45-61
|doi=10.1016/j.techfore.2013.09.020
|subject=Management of Technology and Innovation;Applied Psychology;Business and International Management|+sep=;
|issn=0040-1625

}} {{#scite:

|reference=kitous2010tr
|type=journal-article
|title=Transformation Patterns of the Worldwide Energy System - Scenarios for the Century with the POLES Model
|author=Alban Kitous;Patrick Criqui;Elie Bellevrat;Bertrand Chateau|+sep=;
|journal=The Energy Journal
|publisher=International Association for Energy Economics (IAEE)
|year=2010
|volume=31
|issue=01
|doi=10.5547/issn0195-6574-ej-vol31-nosi-3
|subject=Energy(all);Economics and Econometrics|+sep=;
|issn=0195-6574

}} {{#scite:

|reference=EC 2006
|type=report
|title=World Energy Technology Outlook 2050: WETO H2. [27]
|author=European Commission
|year=2006
|institution=European Commission
|address=Brussels, Belgium

}} {{#scite:

|reference=EC 2003
|type=report
|title=World energy, technology and climate policy outlook 2030: WETO. [28]
|author=European Commission
|year=2006
|institution=European Commission
|address=Brussels, Belgium

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=kriegler2015ma
|type=journal-article
|title=Making or breaking climate targets: The AMPERE study on staged accession scenarios for climate policy
|author=Elmar Kriegler;Keywan Riahi;Nico Bauer;Valeria Jana Schwanitz;Nils Petermann;Valentina Bosetti;Adriana Marcucci;Sander Otto;Leonidas Paroussos;Shilpa Rao;Tabaré Arroyo Currás;Shuichi Ashina;Johannes Bollen;Jiyong Eom;Meriem Hamdi-Cherif;Thomas Longden;Alban Kitous;Aurélie Méjean;Fuminori Sano;Michiel Schaeffer;Kenichi Wada;Pantelis Capros;Detlef P. van Vuuren;Ottmar Edenhofer|+sep=;
|journal=Technological Forecasting and Social Change
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2015
|volume=90
|pages=24-44
|doi=10.1016/j.techfore.2013.09.021
|subject=Management of Technology and Innovation;Applied Psychology;Business and International Management|+sep=;
|issn=0040-1625

}} {{#scite:

|reference=criqui1999ma
|type=journal-article
|title=Marginal abatement costs of CO2 emission reductions, geographical flexibility and concrete ceilings: an assessment using the POLES model
|author=Patrick Criqui;Silvana Mima;Laurent Viguier|+sep=;
|journal=Energy Policy
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=1999
|volume=27
|issue=10
|pages=585-601
|doi=10.1016/s0301-4215(99)00051-8
|subject=Energy(all);Management, Monitoring, Policy and Law|+sep=;
|issn=0301-4215

}}

{{#scite:

|reference=rafaj2012co
|type=journal-article
|title=Co-benefits of post-2012 global climate mitigation policies
|author=Peter Rafaj;Wolfgang Schöpp;Peter Russ;Chris Heyes;Markus Amann|+sep=;
|journal=Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change
|publisher=Springer Nature
|year=2012
|volume=18
|issue=6
|pages=801-824
|doi=10.1007/s11027-012-9390-6
|subject=Ecology;Global and Planetary Change|+sep=;
|issn=1381-2386;1573-1596|+sep=;

}} {{#scite:

|reference=markandya2009pu
|type=journal-article
|title=Public health benefits of strategies to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions: low-carbon electricity generation
|author=Anil Markandya;Ben G Armstrong;Simon Hales;Aline Chiabai;Patrick Criqui;Silvana Mima;Cathryn Tonne;Paul Wilkinson|+sep=;
|journal=The Lancet
|publisher=Elsevier BV
|year=2009
|volume=374
|issue=9706
|pages=2006-2015
|doi=10.1016/s0140-6736(09)61715-3
|subject=Medicine(all)
|issn=0140-6736

}}